A new study has determined the Federal Government could save hundreds of millions of dollars each year without affecting patient outcomes by reducing the private health insurance rebate.
University of Melbourne health economist
Dr Terence Chen's report finds the current 30% means-tested rebate is "expensive and fiscally unsustainable".
You can
listen to an interview with Dr Chen or read his analysis or
view the complete report. Policy contextRising expenditure on health care is expected to put significant pressure on public spending in Australia.
The Intergenerational Report 2010 projects that government spending on health care, as a proportion of Australia’s gross domestic product, is expected to increase from 4.0 percent in 2009–10 to 7.1 percent in 2049–50.
This growth is driven by population ageing, innovation in medical technology, and growing expectations by Australians for high quality health care. This presents an immediate challenge for the government to identify ways to extract maximum value from the health dollars it spends if it is to achieve fiscal sustainability in the longer term.
There has been some progress towards fiscal sustainability by the successful introduction of
means testing for private health insurance rebates and the Medicare Levy Surcharge. This was after two failed attempts to pass the required legislation through parliament in 2009 and 2011.
The introduction of means testing was not without controversy. Representatives of the private health insurance industry strongly opposed the measure, warning about the
catastrophic consequences on the public hospital system. This vastly contrasted with the modelling undertaken by the
Commonwealth Treasury, predicting that the means-test will have little impact on private health insurance coverage,
The current 30% means-tested rebate is expensive and fiscally unsustainable. Are subsidies likely to generate cost savings?Internationally, there is some evidence from the
UKand
Spain that the cost of subsidising private health insurance exceeds the fiscal benefits to the public sector. A reason why this is the case is that individuals are not very price sensitive when it comes to buying health insurance.
Hence a subsidy needs to be sufficiently generous (and expensive) if individuals are to be encouraged to take up private cover.
Recent evidence has shown that Australians are generally not responsive to changes in the price of insurance (e.g. Butler 1999; Frech et al. 2003; Ellis and Savage 2008).
There are a number of reasons why private health insurance in Australia is expected to have small cost-shifting effects. First, private hospitals usually manage patients with comparatively straightforward medical conditions, leaving public hospitals to be responsible for those who require complex and potentially expensive care.
Second, Australians with private health insurance can, and do, continue to use the public system. Third, because doctors can work in
both public and private sectors, expanding the role of private insurance can potentially worsen the burden on the public hospital system if doctors leave the public sector for the private sector.